HOUSEHOLD ECONOMY AND NEW TENDENCIES IN
PRODUCTION COOPERATION IN THE MEKONG DELTA
Do Thai Dong
Institute of Social Sciences
Ho Chi Minh City
1 - The problem of the role of households in agricultural
production was basically solved by Decision No10 of the Central
Committee of Vietnam Communist Party, which recognized the
household's autonomy in production and trade. Many years before, the
ambition of abolishing private peasant ownership led to the idea of
eliminating the household as a basic production unit and to replace
it with compulsory agricultural cooperatives. Practice, however, has
shown that the household economy has a tenacious vitality as it has
since ancient times, and all rural development policies should be
bared on this as a point of departure.
In most cases, our notion of the household economy, especially
households in the Mekong Delta, coincides with the notion of the
peasant family. It is different from western farms not only by
acreage size but also by the way business is conducted. Anyway, the
household economy is a small family economy, which belongs to a
pre-capitalist mode of production. It is not a component of
capitalist market as is the farm economy.
As a production unit, a family in the Mekong Delta does not differ
much from families in northern or central Vietnam. Like others, it is
a unit of land ownership and land use, a unit which carries on
investment and savings. It is also self-financed and self-managed,
balancing its production and consumption, and at the same time it is
a unit which bears all duties before the state. A family itself
decides how to organize the production process, how to use all
abilities among its old and young, male and female members, giving
everybody jobs, and how to balance its labour between different
activities.
Unlike families in cities and industrial areas, rural family is both
a production unit and a living unit at the same time. Those two
functions are not separated, so production is carried on a family
scale, in a family framework and in accordance with family
traditions. This is the historical mode of production in Vietnam's
agriculture, a historically originated type of relations of
production which reflects a certain level of development of
productive forces. Today, as well as in the future, it is impossible
to develop agricultural production and build up rural social life
without this basic family unit concept, with production and everyday
life activities of peasant families which represent the basic of
rural life and agriculture.
What are the constituent factors of the household economy? To answer
this question we need to study the following fundamental factors :
number of people in a family, land stock, number and characters of
labours, sources of funds and means of production, and finally,
sources of income from agricultural and non-agricultural
activities.
There are many surveys done in recent years on the demographic aspect
of the Mekong Delta, which have shown that the household average
demographic size is 5,5 people per unit and that the tendency is to
keep this size stable although sometimes the current land allocation
system, which had taken family size as its main criteria, has
encouraged people to divide families into smaller ones. The average
number of 5,5 people per family was resulted by many socio-economic
factors, especially by population growth rate in last 15 years. It is
noted that families with 4-10 members now make up 85% of the total
number of families in this area. 3% of families have 2 members and
only 2% of families have more than 12 members.
Certainly, the reproduction of generations plays an important role in
maintaining this family size. More than 70% of families consist of 2
generations - parents and their children, while about over 25%
comprise 3 generations . This can be expected to be the picture of
rural family in the long term future. With this family size, people
always have a demographic-labour structure, which is based on the
major labour of husband and wife, and subordinate labour from those
family's member under 16 or over 60 years of age. This also means
that a labourer has two mouths to feed.
Demographic analysis is closely related to analysis of land owned by
families. It is not simple to survey households' land fund changes in
the Mekong Delta due to intricate changes caused by the land
"adjustments" after 1975, through collectivization and equal
distribution of land under Direction No.100 issued by Secretariat of
the Party Central Committee in 1982. Land disputes, which occured
during period 1987-89, revealed those intricate problems.
After promulgation of Decision No.10 on the reform of agricultural
management, a majority of disputes were solved as long as household
rights to long-term land use was recognized. Land law issued in 1992
went further, extending recognition to the rights of land
inheritance, transfer and use as pledge. Actually, land distribution
tends to be determined not by an equality objective, as formerly, but
to be influenced largely by market relations. A land accumulation
process also appears.
However, in order to follow the changes in households' land use in
the Mekong Delta, we need to focus on the whole process through most
important periods. This is closely related and serves as a base for
analysis of rural class structure in Mekong Delta and serves to
forecast future structural changes.
Land reforms, which were implemented by both the revolutionary, as
well as the former Saigon authorities before 1975, have led to
complete abolition of big landlord property holdings. The middle
class, which made up 70% of households in the delta, represents a
relatively stable land distributive situation where the average size
of ownership was below 5 hectares per household in major agricultural
regions. Well-to-do middle households usually concentrated in
economically prosperous regions, where population density was already
high, so that their cultivated acreage rarely could exceed 5
hectares, excluding those who had land under cultivation in wild
areas. The number of landless households make up about three to five
percent and this figure differes through region. The pressure of
population growth in combination with limited available land caused a
decrease in the average cultivated acreage per head in the area along
the Tien river and the Hau river.
Land adjustments in 1978 and agricultural collectivization in 1982
caused serious ups and downs in household land ownership relations,
especially in terms of the middle class. A meticulous survey in Thot
Not district in 1986, which allowed to forecast land disputes latter,
confirmed that 50% of the whole acreage in villages changed hands.
The following is an example of the land ownership picture in a
village with long-standing population in Thot Not district (Phung
village, Thach An commune):
Acreage under cultivation by household use periods:
Period
|
Acreage ('000m2)
|
% of total
|
Before 1975
|
2,093
|
50.67
|
More than 5 years
|
1,660
|
38.58
|
More than 3 year
|
214
|
5.18
|
Less than 3 years
|
142
|
3.44
|
First year
|
22
|
0.53
|
Total
|
4,141
|
100.0
|
Source: Rural survey, made by Do Thai Dong in Thot Not
district, 1986.
Thus, more than 50% of land belonged to households since before 1975.
Changes of land in last 12 years relate to the other half of the
land, major parts of which changed owners in the period 1978-82.
Disputes for land, which occurred since 1987, had led to the complete
collapse of various production brigades and co-operatives formed in
administrative way. Hence, household autonomy in production was
recognized indifferently. In addition, a major part of land, which
changed owners, was returned to its original owners. So far, the
major role in stabilizing land situation in the Mekong Delta belonges
to the peasantry, who themselves carried on negotiations and settled
disputes. However, there still are small land disputes between
members of families.
2 - In fact, Decision No.10 served only as a recognition of land
situation which was formed a long time ago in the Mekong Delta. The
former land situation now appears again in which the over-whelming
majority of households are middle class, including about 10% rich,
70% middle and 20% poor. From now on, land may be reallocated in
accordance with market relations.
However, in the traditional agricultural regions of the Mekong Delta,
land property of 3 to 5 hectares will be a model, which represents a
long term, and almost insurmountable limit for land accumulation.
This, due to many factors, will also be a stable, long-term
cultivated model for prosperous household in the deltas of the Tien
and Hau rivers. The majority of the rest households will have
approximately one hectare of land each and the per capita average
acreage will be about 3,000 m2. This will also be a picture of a
typical middle peasant, the most popular among population in the
Mekong Delta.
So, the Mekong Delta development strategies in the future will face a
class structure, in which the middle peasant household will still be
a major unit of production. Middle peasant households can still reach
a higher production level in many ways. But the size of land
accumulation, if it occurs, has historical limits, which can not be
exceeded to form big farms. The Mekong Delta has historically never
seen a rural bourgeois class. And there is not any sign of the
apperance of a capitalist mode and a bourgeois class in agriculture
yet.
Certainly, differences between different groups of household still
remain, and will become greater. There are many criteria for
household classification, such as the level of market-oriented
production, the income level and finally the ability to turn out
non-agricultural activities together with agricultural ones.
Recently, households, which have proven their abilities and the mode
of market-oriented production, make up only 10% of middle peasant
households in the Mekong Delta. There are many conditions which
converge to raise their abilities of market-oriented production.
The land size is still the crucial condition. Only in newly opened-up
land we can meet households with a big acreage of several tens
hectares and more. But in regions, where the population density is
high, the acreage of 3 hectares under crop and several thousands
square metres of garden is typical size for the solid middle peasant
household. Thus, land fund is one of the fundamental factor, but it
is uncertain that it can determine market-oriented production
abilities of a household.
Capital, which households had saved formerly and stared boldly using
in their business, is the most important factor for households to
prove their actual role in market-oriented production in rural areas.
Although this source of capital is very difficult to measure, reality
shows that peasants spent large amounts of money and gold buying
machinery, transport means and processing workshops, promoting crop
specialization, investing in aquaculture, biding projects in forestry
and fishery, hiring a large number of labour for developing reclaimed
areas.
It is necessary to note that capital use in those cases must be
accompanied by rather thorough knowledge, broad production
experiences, as well as dynamic managerial skills. Those households
which produce for the market usually diversify their activities and
change their targets to satisfy market requirements. Thus, their
technical level of production as well as marketing skills are much
higher than those of other households.
This kind of households represents productive forces of goods in
rural areas, and at the same time it expresses potentials of
structural changes in the rural economy through diversification and
specification, in conjunction with development of processing
industries and industrialization. Hence, despite a small percentage
in whole middle class (10%), those households are the vanguard in
implementing rural development projects in the future.
It is also noted that turning to the market economy, about 40% of the
households in the Mekong Delta will be able to overtake
self-sufficient level and choose a way to develop into market
economy. This kind of households is a major figure in the Mekong
Delta. It is unlike in the situation in the Red River Delta and
Central Vietnam, where poor peasants are considered to be the most
regular in rural areas. Certainly, market-oriented production
capability of those middle peasants is much lower than prosperous
peasants mentioned above.Their land scale is 3 times larger than
average acreage in northern Vietnam, but only about 1 hectare per
household. In areas with high population density, many households
possess only 0.7 hectares of cultivated land, so per capita acreage
falls to less than 2 000 m2. It is difficult for those households to
get funds to buy more land, though when asked, 60% of them want to
have more land for cultivation.
Capital restrictions are more clear. In many cases, households face
difficulties due to lack of money, especially when they need to stage
large investments. Many households have to borrow and seek for
support from rural development credit societies.
From such an aspect as production experiences and knowledge, they are
promising forces in the way of speeding up the development in the
Mekong Delta.
Thus, except prosperous middle households, which make up 50% of the
total number of households, we have 30% of households with production
as well as income level below the average and other 20% of poor
households.
Households below the average can only reach self-sufficiency.
Although they have almost approximate acreage, due to lack of funds
they often have to borrow on high interests. This group is typical
for the rice single crop system, which has no chance to develop other
productive activities. Farming is the sole livelihood for this type
of households. Their per capita income is about $30-40. In difficult
situations caused by natural calamities, they also fall in food
shortage. In several recent years, because of the increase of labour
productivity since decision No.10 and due to positive influence from
export activities, income for those households has increased.
However, in the long run, a prospect of higher living standards will
not be easy if the price of inputs still remains at a high level
while the price of agricultural products may fall.
From such an aspect as the attitude towards development programs,
those households making up 30% of the total await support for
production which can create conditions to bring their own productive
forces into full play and help them to overtake difficulties.
Expected solutions for this vicious circle are not temporary aid or
even short term loans for fertilizers or insecticide purchases.
Peasants sometimes experience all the inconveniences of loan
procedures. The solution is medium and long term measures which
create conditions for them to move forwards applying technical and
scientific progress, carrying on intensive cultivation, specification
and turning to new activities.
20% of the households are poor, with an average per capita income
below 25,000 Dong per month. A survey done by the General Statistical
Office in 1989 and the Policy Department of the Ministry of
Agriculture in 1990 determined the poverty level as a real monthly
per capita income which equals 20 kilograms of rice. In comparison
with this level, the situation in the Mekong Delta was worse. Surveys
had shown that in 1990, the proportion of poor groups among the total
population of the Mekong Delta was almost the same as in northern and
central Vietnam. (For example, in Hau Giang province in 1989 12.1% of
the total households were poor. The similar indicator in Tien Giang
province in 1990 was 15.2%. Meanwhile, the figure for Quang Nam
province was 14.4% and was 14% in Ha Nam Ninh province in 1990). If
compared with the Eastern South, so poor population in Tien Giang
province in 1990 made up 15.2%, may be higher than in Lam Dong
province in the same year - 11.9%.
Despite the fact that the Mekong Delta is the rice bowl of the
country, this region still has hungry people, especially when natural
calamities occur. According to an assessment made by Ministry of
Labour, Invalids and Social Affairs, 6% of the households in this
region are chronically hungry throughout the year. This group
concentrates in areas with aluminous or saline soil where people can
harvest only once a year.
Poor people do not necessary experience a lack of land, but it is a
fact that they use land inefficiently. Lack of funds is also one of
the reasons. But first of all, this often is the situation when
hunger leads households to short term borrowings for very high
interest rates so that later they have to pay debts by selling out
young paddy and reach a deadlock. It is necessary to note that in the
Mekong Delta usury is very serious and almost a custom. Interest
rates may reach the level of 20% or even 30% per month. Social evils
such as gambling and drinking, together with illiteracy are other
factors explaining poverty in the Mekong Delta.
Being a hired labourer is one of the ways for poor people to earn
their living and this is popular in the Mekong River Delta. The
phenomenon of a hired agricultural worker, who has no land and no
properties, but has an income above the average, sometimes is highly
praised. There are different points of view about this phenomenon.
Supporters of land accumulation explain that it is an inevitable
process in which land is accumulated by households, who are able to
use it more efficiently. Other people say that this phenomenon indeed
causes anxiety, because it creates social differentiation and
increases the number of rural proletariat, who do not have stable
earnings. Both points of view are reasonable to some extend, if we
consider only the land factor and exclude all other possibilities,
which could play a more significant role in solving the problem of
surplus labour in rural areas.
Certainly, there are other factors, which must be considered
carefully. For example, if the land accumulation process goes too
quickly, it will inevitably cause social troubles due to the
polarization of the rich and poor. In some places the numbers of
households who have sold all of their land has reached 15-20% of the
total population. This figure causes anxiety. Also, it is necessary
to take practical and immediate measures to alleviate hunger, and to
reduce the debts of peasants to usurers. An initiative in mobilizing
credit for poor people would be very helpful now, especially in the
poorest regions. If activities of local authorities to alleviate
poverty could become more effective, it also could contribute to
finding more immediate measures to reduce difficulties in the poorest
group.
However, in the long run, problems of surplus labour and reduced land
under cultivation caused by population growth, will demand more
fundamental development measures. These measures must aim to create
alternative sources of income, firstl from agricultural activities
and then from non-agricultural ones.
In agriculture at the present time, 50% of households have only two
sources of income: first, from rice cultivation, and second, from pig
raising. Very few households could turn poultry or cattle raising, or
fishing into major sources of income. Almost all poor households have
only one source of income. They are totally dependant on the rice
crop. Even amongst middle peasant households, it is noted that only
60% have stable incomes from pig raising, and 8% from poultry
raising. Households who cultivate fruit on such a scale that it
becomes a major source of income, usually are concentrated in several
regions which have traditions in this kind of cultivation, and have
access to markets. Regarding fishery activities, a survey in South
Mang Thit, a region with a maritime economy, showed that only 8% of
households have regular incomes from fish and shrimp raising.
Income from non-agricultural activities contributed an even smaller
proportion. Only prosperous villagers can turn to non-agricultural
activities and agricultural services. Very few people can do business
in trading tractor ploughs, harrows and other agricultural machinery.
Numbers of people involved with agricultural services is also
restricted by the small scale of activities, and in many case, those
people are dependent on traders. Food processing and other small
industries have started thriving in rural areas. However, middle
peasant households, or even prosperous ones are not able to develop
steadily their household economy.
3 - We can see from the above facts that to turn a household into a
factor for development in the future, to change the nature of the
household income structure, to help households to generate savings
and to be able to solve essential problems of surplus of labour, it
is clear that we have to solve problems outside of the household
framework. How to organize the current economy so that it integrates
household resources, agriculture and industry. Thus, inevitably it
touches upon problems of cooperativization and industrialization in
rural areas.
When production reaches a certain level, it will automatically bring
about the development of co-operative structures. This happens
inevitably in the process of socializing production. Every household,
even if it is given the maximum autonomy in production, has a limited
space for development, especially in the market mechanism. A
household, which lacks , the means of production, or information,
will not be able to meet requirements of the market with its changing
completlity. Hence, households themselves need to co-operate.
In other countries, there are various co-operative forms and
co-operatives in every field of production and trade. Those
co-operatives sometimes are large, just like unions of producers in
agriculture. Some co-operatives are able to control the markets for
agricultural products. They just integrate agriculture and industry
in order to supply goods in large quantities and with high commercial
value. Due to their power, co-operatives can defend the interests of
agricultural interests in the market.
In Vietnam, compulsory co-operativization was applied for a period of
time. Especially in the Mekong Delta, collectivization had deprived
households of autonomy, hence incurring deep displeasure and
negativity from the peasantry. However, today after households were
given autonomy in production, forms of co-operation of production
under different names started to appear again. Focusing on these
co-operative forms, we can derive the following features.
The membership of co-operatives is made up of households.
Co-operation is completely voluntarily, and is initiated and
established by households, without any intervention from the
authorities. The field for co-operation is very concrete. It aims at
some production or trading activity such as cultivation of new crops,
application of a new breed, raising of fish, shrimp, milch cow,
services like tillage, applying fertilizer and plant protection.
Management is very simple, and management methods may be changed to
achieve greater efficiency, without any bureaucratic mechanism.
Co-operatives defend the interest of the peasantry against pressures
from private traders, by using different arrangements for input
supply through direct relationship with large companies. They also
take responsibility for getting loans and credits from banks, helping
their members to use these sources of funds efficiently, and
supervising in-time payment of debt.
Many forms of co-operative groups of production have developed in
different regions. For example, a recent survey in An Giang province
revealed that the province has 2,191 co-operative groups of
production, attracting 78,952 households, and occupying 41.1% of
cultivated acreage - 70,289 hectares. 50% of households who are
raising fish, pigs, cows, have joined co-operative groups for animal
husbandry in order to make it more convenient to receive new
techniques and to take an active role in the marketing of their
outputs.
Making an assessment of this new tendency, the An Giang Provincial
Rural Development Program had made the following remarks:
1) Peasant households have become autonomous units, and now,
step-by-step turn into commodity producers. Co-operativization does
not mean the abolishment of individual household economies, as with
former thinking, but on the contrary, it aims at helping the
household economy, and facilitating the development of the household
economy.
2) Co-operation is based on the social division of labour, and hence
it facilitates the appearance of increasingly specialized production
and service entities.
3) Co-operativization in the market economy does not mean the
abolishment of private ownership and private interests. Contrarily,
it is necessary to exploit private interests as a motive force for
production development, bringing into play the spirit of co-operation
between the peasantry.
4) The co-operative is an important link for speeding up
scientific-technical progress, acting as a base for technological
transfer and technical diffusion in rural areas.
To sum up, new co-operative forms started their first steps under
favorable conditions. They brought with them the practical efficiency
of production and trade. However, it is too early to say that these
co-operation forms will develope further by themselves. In fact,
these forms appear in very small numbers and they lack full capacity
in terms of fundamental development targets.
Rural economic infrastructure in the Mekong Delta still remains very
weak. To develop infrastructure, it is expected that people's savings
may be partially mobilized and used by co-operatives. But the
government still plays a key role in supporting co-operatives,
helping to supply them with technical equipment for increasingly
specialized sectors. Governmental support given to co-operatives is
not subsidized. It comprises loans, tax policy, protection of the
market for their products, import of technical equipment, and
especially the supply of intellectual labour, including technical and
managerial. The goal is to advance co-operatives step-by-step from
scattered units to a co-operative network, which comprises
large-scale production and trading systems.
Government plays an especially important role in agricultural
financial support policy. Co-operatives will be major objects for
effective implementation of the policy, whose goal is to thoroughly
develop the entire rural sector.
In the beginning, financial support usually aims at immediate
household needs. Loans are between several hundred thousand to a
million dong, at current price levels. This amount is just enough for
a household to meet everyday consumption needs or to purchase inputs
(seeds, fertilizer, fuel). With such a small amount, a household can
also pay debts to credit societies or rural development banks.
However, later it will be more important that loans and funds from
rural banks and credit societies will be used for relatively big
projects, which are scheduled to be implemented by co-operatives.
Loans will also be made through credit co-operatives, whose funds
come from the contributions of peasants contribution and agricultural
funding. In the future, the World Bank, the Asian Development Bank,
as well as other foreign banks also can finance large-scale projects
through large co-operatives in animal husbandry, rice and fruit
exports, forestry, etc.
In fact, when the peasantry's internal savings will be greater, the
co-operative role in attracting this source of funds will be much
more important. Foreign experiences show that if there are not
projects which can attract this source of funds to develop the local
economy, peasants will send most of their savings to big cities to
benefit from non-agricultural activities. Hence the government should
have medium- and long-term development programs to support
co-operatives in circulating peasant's funds, which cannot be done
efficiently by single households.